David Webb's submission to The Stock Exchange of Hong Kong on what later became GEM.

Response to consultation paper on a Proposed New Market for Emerging Companies
20 July 1998

This paper constitutes my submission in relation to the Consultation Paper dated May 1998 ("CP"). To aid the assimilation of comments, I will try to follow the enumeration of the questions set out in paragraph CP(20).

  1. Is there a need for a Second Market?

    Yes, but whether we can satisfy this need depends on the framework of the Second Market. If we fail to set the correct framework then the need for such a market will not be satisfied.

    It is certainly the case that HK lacks a transparent forum for the issuance and trading of equity in venture capital and start-up companies. Other territories have found a demand for such markets and I do not believe HK to be so different as to lack such a need. However, the profile of such companies will differ greatly from, say, NASDAQ, as HK does not have a major presence in the software, hardware or biotechnology markets. By contrast, we may see listings of "theme" restaurant chains or shops, which would help capitalise our tourism-related industry.

  2. Should the market target only sophisticated investors?

    This question has its roots in the fact that when people lose money they often seek to blame authorities. This is natural, but we cannot close the markets to prevent this. Complaints are a sign of a healthy market economy and an open society. If companies never went bankrupt then the economy would be dysfunctional.

    In the equity markets, we must be careful to discriminate between complaints which arise from fraud, malfeasance, or loopholes in regulations, and those which arise from simply failed investments. For example, C.A. Pacific's clients' losses have nothing to do with risky investments, but with questions of regulation and supervision of money lending and the terms on which client assets can be "borrowed" by brokers and used as collateral for their own financing. We should not allow situations like C.A. Pacific to cloud our vision on the classes of permissible investments.

    I think the framework of the market should be such that investors are made clearly aware of the risks of investing in such stocks, but not prevented from doing so. The CP(5.1) attempts to define sophisticated investors as "professional and knowledgeable retail investors". What is a "knowledgeable retail investor"? Is this one who is rich? Or a graduate with an MBA? Or someone who reads the Asian Wall Street Journal? Of course, we should aim to make all investors more knowledgeable, but we should not seek to "target" investors by means of financial entry barriers, or identify who is sophisticated and who is not.

    It must be recognised that the Main Board already has an open market in securities which as a class are more risky than equities on the Second Market, namely derivative warrants and company warrants. These are highly geared instruments and investors may lose their entire investments (most expiring warrants this year are worthless). We do not seek to prevent investors from assuming this risk. If we are going to permit the general public to invest in warrants, or highly geared companies, then they should be allowed to assume the lower risks of the Second Market. However, one of the key principles of modern portfolio theory is that investors should diversify their risk for a given expected return. To set a large minimum transaction size would make this difficult for all but the rich (see later).

    If the Exchange decides to pursue the "sophisticated investor" route then I urge that this be done by more conventional means. I am not aware of any other jurisdiction which approaches the problem with the "brute force" approach of prohibitive investment size. The more normal approach is proposed in CP(9) and I support this as perfectly workable. Risk warnings can be repeated on contract notes, as on the second board in other jurisdictions.

    An alternative would be to require (i) investors to pass an exam; and/or (ii) investors to sign a declaration that they have net worth greater than a certain figure. The first is costly to implement, while the second is very difficult to verify.

  3. Is raising the minimum transaction size an effective barrier for entry for uninformed and rumour-driven investors?

    Not entirely. To answer "yes" would be to presume that the poor have a monopoly on stupidity. It would certainly prohibit the poorer ones, but those that could afford just one board lot (at $250,000) would be placing 100% of their portfolio in one company. If the ignorant are going to invest, then I would rather they invested $25,000 in each of 10 companies. This is much more diversified and the chance of losing the entire investment is close to zero.

    CP(6) seeks to justify the minimum transaction size proposal by reference to the "circumstances prevailing in Hong Kong" and that "comparison...with any of the second market models in other jurisdictions is not thought to be meaningful". What makes us so special? We do not have a monopoly on speculative behaviour - this is basic human nature. Markets around the region and the world have similar characteristics in this regard. A comparison with these presumably shows that the large board lot scheme is unconventional.

    We should also bear in mind that large transaction size does not appear to be a deterrent in other forms of speculative behaviour, such as property investment. In repeated cycles, people have been quite happy to risk the deposit on a pre-sale flat, or even purchase the right to buy one, knowing they may lose their entire investment. If these types of investors hear a "sure-fire tip" on a Second Market stock, they would still find a way to buy one board lot, and may even syndicate the purchase among their friends and relatives, increasing the number of persons at risk.

  4. What should be the minimum transaction size ($100-150K, $150-200K, $200-250K or an amount above $250K)?

    None of the above. The question unfortunately pre-supposes that a large minimum transaction size ("MTS") is the way to go. It also suggests that board lots are necessary, an issue which I deal with later. My answer on the MTS depends in part on the trading system.

    If a stock market uses a "firm" trading system (where the buy or sell order is displayed and is binding if "hit") then of course it needs to set a MTS, to avoid people moving the nominal price with a bid or offer for 1 share, or hitting a bid or offer with just 1 share, which causes minimum brokerage charges which can be larger than the value of the share traded. The Main Board suffers from the current 2,000 share board lot used by most new issuers, because if a buyer who is bidding for $10,000 of stock (at say $0.50 per share) gets "hit" with a single sale of 2,000 shares worth $1,000, then his minimum brokerage charge (typically $100) will amount to 10% of the cost, not 1%. This happens more often in small-caps where the market is less liquid. The small MTS is also used to manipulate closing prices.

    So if the trading system is "firm" I think the minimum transaction size displayed should be around $10,000, something which does not produce excessive brokerage charges as a percentage of the investment. Transactions above this size should be in any number of whole shares.

    However, the CP(17) proposes an "indicative" trading system where indications of interest are posted on a bulletin board. In this case, all bargains are by negotiation, and there is no need to specify a MTS. Brokers simply effect best execution for their clients. If a client only wants 850 shares, he can post this interest. If he has an odd number of shares due to a history of rights issues or bonus issues, he can offer this number of shares. There is no need for separate screens for "whole lots" and "odd lots". This logic also applies to the Main Board, although it does need a MTS because it is a "firm" system. Once investors get comfortable with this concept, they will have no difficulty with it.

    If the Exchange goes for a $250K minimum transaction size (and a board lot of this value), then consider these problems:

    1. If the minimum free float is $30m, then there may only be 120 board lots in the float. As some larger or institutional investors will buy several lots, a company may only have about 50 shareholders at any time, or barely the minimum number proposed by the Exchange.
    2. Each holder of one lot cannot just sell part of his holding if it goes up, he has to sell the whole lot. He may hold on longer rather than do this, increasing his exposure.
    3. A potential investor who wants to take a position in the stock, but is uncertain of the fair price or market outlook, would have to buy a whole lot, rather than employ a more prudent and gradual approach to investing, such as "dollar cost averaging". In summary of (4.1) to (4.3), large board lots make for "lumpy" and inefficient investment with friction in the market.
    4. If an issuer wishes to declare a scrip dividend or a rights issue or a bonus issue (other than a very large N:1 issue) then almost every shareholder would end up with odd lots, and the odd-lot board would become more important than the normal trading screen. The only winners would be brokers who buy and consolidate odd-lots at big discounts due to the lack of transparency and liquidity in fractional lots.
    5. If an issuer declares a rights issue, then the nil-paid rights would have a much smaller board lot value and higher risk, as they are just short-term call warrants. Would the Exchange prohibit such trading? Or prevent new investors from buying the rights? Presumably not.
    6. The Exchange survey indicates that the average retail portfolio size is $150,000 and the average transaction size is $50,000. These are very precise figures and I would be interested to know what the sample size and methodology was, as well as the median and standard deviation of responses. Assuming that the figures are correct, then this indicates an average of 3 investments (assuming each "transaction" is in a different stock) which is a highly concentrated portfolio with a large element of non-market risk. Portfolio theory states that non-market risk is not rewarded, since it can be avoided. The Exchange should be encouraging portfolio diversification, but a large MTS would discourage or prevent diversification. Regulators will receive fewer complaints about failed investments if the amounts involved are a smaller proportion of investors'; portfolios.

    Board lots are anachronistic

    Although the use of board lots implies a minimum transaction size, the setting of a minimum transaction size does not imply the need for board lots.

    There is no logical reason why transaction sizes can't be in any whole number of shares above the minimum. The board lot itself is an out-dated concept which arose from the way stocks were once settled here (B.C. - Before CCASS). Each board lot was represented by a separate share certificate, and investors settled sales by the delivery of a number of share certificates equal to the number of board lots sold. These huge piles of paper were passed around the market with executed transfer deeds, between a long sequence of buyers and sellers, until a book closure date approached, at which time they would all come in for registration. Registrars charged per board lot certificate, thus ensuring great profitability. Between book close dates, the passing of lots in "street name" allowed rapid settlement (and hence re-sale) without registration. It is fair to say this facilitated speculative trading, because a new holder was not "locked in" pending registration.

    In some other markets (e.g. London), even before they adopted "scripless" trading, the alternative system was followed. Namely, trades were in any whole number of shares, not lots. If a shareholder sold shares, his single share certificate was sent to the registrar for transfer, and a new one issued in the name of the transferee. If he had sold only part of his holding, the holding would be "split" and a new certificate issued to each party. This system also made it easier for companies to communicate with registered shareholders, as compared with Hong Kong, where the register was always far out of date.

    Now we have moved from B.C. to A.D. (After Demobilisation). All trades pass through CCASS for settlement, and most transactions are settled by book-entry, without the need for movement or registration of scrip, which remains in the vaults of CCASS, registered in the name of HKSCC Nominees Ltd. All of the historic reasons for use of board lots are gone (except, perhaps, the love of registrars for printing paper). So I think the Second Market should be traded in any whole number of shares, subject to a minimum only if the trading system is "firm".

  5. Are the proposed entry requirements appropriate for the Second Market?

    Not in all respects.

    I disagree with CP(8.2(ii)), where free floats must be at least 35% of the company. There is no logic in this, and at no point in the paper does the Exchange explain or justify it. I presume the intention is to encourage a liquid market in the shares and one which is less open to manipulation. However, the percentage of the company which is public has no bearing on this except to the extent of its dollar value, which is dealt with by the $30m minimum.

    If a company is expected to have a market value of, say, $400m, then would the Exchange still require a 35% float of $140m? This would be almost 3 times the Main Board minimum of $50m. We should recognise that float size in small or medium sized companies is not an impediment to speculation or manipulation, and only has a deterrent effect at much higher levels. Pearl Oriental and Leading Spirit were once much larger companies than they are now, as was Beijing Enterprises, but the Exchange knows the story.

    The true way to deter speculation and manipulation is better disclosure by issuers, directors and shareholders (see proposed SDI reforms) and investor education on stock valuation methods. Manipulators would not be so profitable if investors were more educated.

    To impose a 35% float may deter companies from floating, because this reduces their ability to raise equity in the future without losing control. I note that the lower limit in other markets ranges from none to 25%.

    Restrictions on Share Disposals

    A further problem in CP(8.3) is the provision that loans secured on management shares must be "taken for the direct benefit of the Company". This provision should be removed, as it could, for example, prevent Management Buy-Outs (MBOs) from subsequently going public. The directors would have bought the company and pledged their lives and shares to finance the purchase, and such a loan does not "directly benefit the Company".

    Issue of New Shares Only

    In relation to CP(8.5), the Exchange should realise that promoters can remove cash by large pre-IPO dividends or asset purchases, and this is a regular practice on the Main Board so as to avoid the direct appearance of "selling into the IPO". Therefor such a rule banning sales at the time of the listing would have no real effect. However, the rule may make it difficult for financial investors such as venture capitalists to realise part of their investment, and this is not a good thing, since this may discourage them from investing in the first place, or it may force issuers to list on overseas markets instead. I think the Exchange should not include this rule. If investors are told that management or financial shareholders are selling through the IPO, then they will take this into account in deciding whether to purchase/ subscribe for the shares.

    Limit on public shareholdings

    CP(8.6) proposes that "no single public shareholder will be allowed to hold more than 10% of the issued share capital". This seems unworkable (except at the time of listing). At the least, it would require amendments to the law, as the Exchange cannot regulate investors, only issuers. The articles of the issuer could contain a restriction on transfers, but this would not prevent nominees or companies under common control from collectively owning more than 10%. In any case, most shares will be in CCASS and not subject to transfer on the share register.

    This seems like an effort to address the "Pricerite" problem, where an investor acquired more than 10% of the company, and the Exchange decided to suspend the shares because this reduced the "free float" below 25%. Other exchanges have long since recognised that it is not in the interests of minority shareholders to do this as it deprives them of a transparent market in which to sell their shares, and may encourage off-market trading. One can simply warn them that trading may become less liquid and/or prices may become more volatile, but it is better to have whatever trading there is on the market, where it can be seen.

    During the early 1980s, car giant British Leyland was over 99% owned by the UK Government, having been bailed out, but the listing was maintained and trading continued at a low level of liquidity.

  6. Is it acceptable that the Principal Shareholders should be required to lock up their shares? Are the proposed lock up periods for the Management Shareholders and Financial Shareholders appropriate?

    Yes and Yes. However, this should not prohibit sales as part of the IPO (see above).

  7. Is the "let the buyer beware" approach underpinning much of the additional disclosure requirement acceptable?

    Yes.

  8. Is the concept of "Active Business Pursuits" as an alternative to the current requirement to show a three year profit track record acceptable?

    Yes.

  9. Is the Statement of Business Objectives required by investors and/or is it too onerous or impractical for issuers to satisfy?

    I think it will certainly assist investors to make a better assessment of the company's prospects and of the degree of clarity of the management's strategy. It is not too onerous or impractical, but post-vetting of this part of the prospectus will have to be gentle, since it is clearly difficult to determine objectively whether disclosure is sufficient.

  10. Are the continuing reporting requirements... too onerous?

    No. Quarterly reporting should also be required on the Main Board.

    Furthermore, the reporting must be more punctual - 5 months is too long to wait for final results. I suggest 3 months for final audited results and 2 months for the other 3 quarters. A preliminary, unaudited final result (subject to adjustment) could also be required within 2 months of the year-end. If these timeframes are a problem, then the company lacks adequate controls and internal information systems and is not suitable for listing.

  11. Are the eligibility criteria proposed for Sponsors appropriate?

    Not in all respects.

    $50m is a lot of money, and is more than is needed to run and maintain a financial adviser. If the Exchange sets this as an on-going obligation (as proposed) then the entry barrier is more like $70m to provide for possible start-up operating losses.

    In other markets, it has been recognised that sponsoring second board issues is intensive and low-margin work, and that therefor it is unattractive to big investment firms to do this work. What happens is that experienced professionals summon up the courage to leave the big firms and set up their own firms and take on this work at lower costs. Boutique advisers spring up to service the new market. They cannot do this if they have to inject $70m of capital into the business.

    I think $15m is a more sensible level, if a limit must be set. A typical start-up might need 6 professionals at an average salary of $800,000 per year, plus about 1,000 sq. ft. of office space at $10/sf/month (they don't have to be in Central), plus sundry overheads of say $1m per year. This makes a total operating cost of about $6m p.a. plus bonuses (if profitable). So we can see that if a Sponsor does one IPO and then spends the next two years printing red ink it would not run out of capital.

    In proposing this limit I am of course not commenting on underwriting capacity. Issues may or may not be underwritten, and in particular in the case of selective marketings (placings) this is not wholly necessary. Instead, a minimum subscription target can be set and if not achieved, the issue does not proceed. Alternatively, the role of adviser and underwriter may be separated.

    I wholly support the criteria for experienced staffing of such firms. Indeed, in CP(11.2(vii)) I think that each issue should be under the direct responsibility of a director, not just a "supervisor". The directors of a Sponsor must not be allowed to claim that they were not "directly involved" with their clients when things go wrong. Furthermore, directors of sponsors are more likely to be around to write the report after 2-3 years.

  12. Is it adequate that the Exchange would only review a preliminary notification of listing and examine Listing Documents for the purpose of ensuring compliance with the Companies Ordinance?

    No. The claim that the "Exchange is not equipped to assess commercial aspects of applicants" has no real bearing. The same could be said of applicants for the Main Board. Businesses listing on the Second Market will not differ so much in their commercial activity from those on the Main Board.

    It is a regrettable fact that many sponsors in HK, even on the Main Board, allow inadequate or superficial disclosure in their prospectuses. I know, because I read most of them. If the Exchange did not take part in this process then things would be even worse. Even now, there is a practical issue that the line staff of the Listing Division often have no commercial experience, nor have they worked in sponsors, so they can't always spot the real issues and just rigorously follow check-lists. A program of secondments from the Exchange to some of the higher quality sponsors (and vice versa) might help to strengthen the vetting process.

    In short, I think the Exchange has to stay in the loop. The other problem with post-vetting is that whether a particular requirement (such as "Active Business Pursuits") has been adequately met is a subjective matter, and a Sponsor would not want to be at risk of censure if the Exchange disagreed that it had satisfied the requirement, since this could put them out of business. Sponsors would rather hear objections before listing is granted.

  13. Are the proposed corporate governance requirements appropriate?

    Yes in most respects, but not in others.

    Multiple directorships

    In reference to CP(13.2(iii)) I think the terms of qualification of Independent Non-executive Directors ("INEDs") should be strengthened. Many companies on the Main Board have the same INEDs as companies under common control, which means that a more material portion of that person's income may be derived from their fees than if they only sat on one board. This leads to a "cosier" relationship, since the controlling shareholders are in practice able to determine the appointment and resignation of INEDs. If the Exchange does not believe this, then notice how often the INEDs change whenever there is a change of control of an issuer. The Rules should be changed so that a person who is an INED of a company may not sit on the board of any other company under the same control. Furthermore, Executive Directors of separate companies should not "swap seats" and sit on each other's boards as INEDs, since this is obviously a mutually beneficial arrangement.

    Professional conflicts

    INEDs on the Main Board are often partners or solicitors in legal advisers (or sometimes auditors) to the company. While it is good to have a lawyer or accountant as an INED, it should not be one whose firm (often very small) receives fees from the company for advice or other services, since this is a conflict of interest. If such an INED does not "behave", his firm may lose a client (or several in the same group).

    Fitness

    Thirdly, if INEDs are to be effective then they need to have a working knowledge of the corporate governance regime and legal framework of Hong Kong. A physician who lives in Canada or a bureaucrat from Fujian province do not fit these criteria. They are likely to be "men of straw" who will always be "uncontactable" in responsibility statements and will generally sign anything they are asked to, and resign at the first sign of trouble.

    Some thought needs to be given to how to resolve this problem. Personally, I think INEDs should be required to sit some sort of short course on their duties and obligations (perhaps a set of seminars or video tapes to be arranged by the SEHK), be resident in Hong Kong, and be between the ages of 30 and 70 inclusive. Currently it is probably easier to become an INED than it is to get a liquor licence or a driving licence, but I think INEDs carry a greater responsibility as the eyes and ears of minority shareholders.

    Election of INEDs

    The election of INEDs at AGMs (either those who are elected for the first time, those who are up for re-election, or those appointed by the board since the last AGM) should be voted upon by independent shareholders only. It is a glaring contradiction in the current Rules that the INEDs can be re-elected by the controlling shareholders and executive directors. If independent shareholders are not satisfied with their representatives, there is nothing they can do about it. All the INEDs have to do is "behave" to get their fees for the next year.

    It is better to allow independent shareholders the right to remove INEDs (and elect others in their place), since it is the independent shareholders that the INEDs are representing.

    All shareholder resolutions on connected transactions and election of INEDs should be put to a poll, for the reasons explained at length in my earlier paper.

    Executive Directors' compensation

    CP(13.3) proposes a requirement that compensation increases not provided for in the prospectus should be approved by the Audit and Compliance Committee ("ACC"). CP(13.2 (iv)) proposes that the ACC would be chaired by an INED. This proposal does not go far enough, since the Executive Directors would still be in a majority on the ACC. Even if the ACC were to comprise only the 2 INEDs, they would still have little incentive to control pay.

    Compensation increases in the US and UK are proof that boards tend to choose their salaries and then find an "industry norm" to justify them to their independent committees, many of whom are also executive directors of other listed companies and therefor sympathise. "Compensation experts" are often hired (at the company's expense) who have a direct incentive (their fee) to come up with generous recommendations.

    It is better to make it a mandatory requirement that the prospectus stipulates (i) a maximum annual percentage for compensation increase; and (ii) a maximum percentage of pre-tax profits to be paid as bonuses, and that any subsequent variation of this be approved by independent shareholders as a "connected transaction" (on a poll). After all, such variations confer a direct benefit on the executive directors. This approach should also be adopted on the Main Board. Shareholders will not be averse to approving profit-related pay or share option schemes if the INEDs advise them that they are fair and reasonable.

    Suspension Policy

    An "Exchange source" has been giving briefings recently in a number of newspaper articles. I don't know why he declines to be named - is this "stealthy regulation"? The Exchange seems to have taken the view that after a suspension, dealings can only resume upon the request of the issuer. This is bizarre. The issuer remains subject to its disclosure obligations under the Listing Agreement, so I see no reason why the Exchange cannot "throw the switch" on the computer and allow trading to resume. Registration of transfers is presumably not a problem since the law and articles do not permit book closure for longer than 30 days in any year.

    In other jurisdictions, the suspension and resumption of trading is at the discretion of the exchange or the securities regulator and does not require the issuer's consent, although suspension by such authorities must of course be justifiable.

    Shareholders' Disclosures

    The Exchange may find practical problems with putting a 5% disclosure requirement in constitutional documents. At best, such a requirement can only be contractually binding on the registered shareholders, who are legally the members of the company. These will seldom be the beneficial owners - most public shares will be registered in the name of HKSCC Nominees Ltd. Therefor such a disclosure obligation would have no force until it became law.

  14. Is it appropriate to give [independent] shareholders the opportunity to wind up a company...?

    Yes, but this is a very serious situation as it is likely to lead to a loss of some business with suppliers and customers of the group. Even the proposal of such a resolution would immediately impact on the business of the group. Therefor I think the criterion in CP(13.4(i)) (any public censure) is not sufficient. As soon as a public censure had been made, the company would be at risk of liquidation. This in turn may make the Exchange more reluctant to use the tool of Public Censure except in extreme circumstances, which would restrict the ability to regulate.

    Such a resolution should be put to a poll or it will be an ineffective rule. In the relevant circular, an Independent Financial Adviser should be required to provide an explanation of the effects of winding up and give an opinion as to the likely net proceeds if (a) the business and assets of the company are sold as a going concern or (b) the business is closed and liquidated. Option (b) could of course lead to much lower proceeds. The INEDs should also be required to give their recommendations to independent shareholders on the appropriate course of action (having received such advice). One possibility (effectively part of (a)) is that the controlling shareholders may choose to submit a privatisation proposal, which they are always free to do.

    It is likely that all the business and assets of a listed issuer would be held via a wholly-owned subsidiary, so that a winding-up order on the parent would not directly affect the subsidiaries, and would permit them to be sold as going concerns.

    If shareholders vote in favour of a winding-up, then the company will have to go through the voluntary winding-up process of the jurisdiction in which the company is domiciled. This will normally involve the appointment of a liquidator. The Exchange should consider the legal aspects of this process in each jurisdiction before permitting listing of companies domiciled in that jurisdiction, and Hong Kong is no exception. Offshore domiciles such as Bermuda may present practical difficulties as all court proceedings would take place there.

  15. Should consideration be given to facilitate the current winding up process given that this could give rise to practical difficulties and delays?

    I'm not sure I understand the question. If "current winding up process" means the formal winding-up process of the courts, then is the Exchange suggesting changes to the winding up procedures of the Companies Ordinance? Or the Bermuda Companies Act? This would be ambitious.

  16. Is a display-of-interest trading medium appropriate for the Second Market?

    Yes, but the displays of interest need to be visible to the public to reduce the risk of rat-trading and front-running.

  17. Should the Second Market allow overseas incorporated companies to list and if so what should be the additional requirements?

    Yes, same as for the Main Board, subject to the Exchange's investigation of the winding-up process in that jurisdiction as discussed in answer (14) above.

  18. Would many companies be deterred from listing on the Second Market because of high costs?

    No. They may have other reasons, but companies which meet the entry criteria should be able to bear the costs.

  19. (a) Should the Second Market be an entirely distinct market from the Main Board? (b) Would it be sufficient for the Exchange to either lower its Main Board's listing requirements or introduce a new Chapter under the current Exchange Listing Rules to accommodate smaller companies?
    1. Yes, it should be distinct.
    2. No, this would not be sufficient. I wholly agree with the Exchange's views that the Second Market must be a recognisable separate entity. This makes it far clearer to investors that they are taking on a separate class of risk assets by investing in such companies.

Further remarks

I would be happy to discuss and explain my views verbally on any of the matters raised in this submission. Please feel free to contact me.

Back to top

© Webb-site.com, 1998


Organisations in this story

Topics in this story


Sign up for our free newsletter

Recommend Webb-site to a friend

Copyright & disclaimer, Privacy policy

Back to top